This week’s readings, the topic of which might be
labelled “the politics of Social Innovation,” outline a variety of debates
surrounding the strategies with which we pursue—and funding with which we
support—social innovation. With the exception of Brown’s article on Finland
(which serves as an interesting juxtaposition), they are primarily focused on
US policies. And most of the articles make a case, to varying degrees, for the
potential of social innovation, with the exception of the National Review’s
cheap and transparent hackery.
Mentioned in a few of the articles is one of the
U.S. government’s better-known social-impact channels: AmeriCorps. AmeriCorps
refers to a diverse body of programs all over the country who do a variety of socially beneficial work. AmeriCorps is managed by the Corporation for
National and Community Service (CNCS), which also oversees the US Social Innovation
Fund. I’ve served in two AmeriCorps programs, and am a proud alumnus.
One of the AmeriCorps programs in which I served was
the National Civilian Community Corps (or, NCCC). NCCC, which received a
specific callout in the National Review article, is the current reincarnation
of FDR’s Civilian Conservation Corps—a cornerstone of the New Deal, notable for
projects like the Hoover Dam and various state parks, that was disbanded when
the US entered World War II, but which at its peak employed millions of Americans in
meaningful work. NCCC (the current version, “N-Triple-C,” as it’s said) was
created by George H. W. Bush’s administration in 1992 and was incorporated into
AmeriCorps, founded a year later under Clinton. What’s interesting to note
about NCCC is that, despite being rooted in one of the most successful social
programs in history (that is, anywhere), it lacks the funding to provide more
than 1,000-or-so positions annually—even though it regularly gets around 10
times that many applications (and that, without much of a marketing campaign to
speak of). It works, it’s incredibly cost-efficient, it generates enormous
impact, and many more people want to join. Granted, I’m a little biased, but this a
pretty clear example of a no-brainer.
Yet instead of fighting for funding to expand, NCCC
has to return to congress nearly every year just to fight to survive.
And NCCC is just one example of many organizations in a similar boat—organizations
with programs that work and have the potential to grow, likely generating an
incredible return on investment to society, but which find themselves spending a
great deal of energy just justifying their own existence.
The Skoll article in Forbes suggests three key
elements to the process of generating social innovation: invention, evidence,
and resources. It then lays out a path through which the US government could
attempt to improve its support of social innovation, which includes: expanding
existing programs, supporting efficient management practices, and implementing
a pro-innovation culture throughout the government. I agree with the spirit of
those suggestions, but it seems that a glaring obstacle has not been addressed.
In today’s increasingly insular and partisan politics, fueled by a culture with
the news-consuming attention span a squirrel-obsessed dog, how do you break
through? More than one in five children in America are born into poverty, yet the
gun lobby in America—the country with the most formally entrenched protections
on gun ownership anywhere—is far more powerful than the, let’s say, poverty
lobby—to whatever extent the latter even exists.
How do we position ourselves to better support
social innovation? I’m sure I don’t have a cogent answer to that question, but
I propose that the follow-up questions should not be primarily logistical, as implied
in most of this week’s readings. Evidence-based practice seems like an intuitive
response to a lack of public interest. (Let's quantify the impact and thereby, convince people to invest public resources, or so go the argument.) But in this case, the lack of public
interest is far more fundamental. We need a revolution in compassion in this
country, and it will take more than a subtle campaign. Last week, Professor Zak
topically suggested there’s a Nobel Prize in economics waiting for the person
who can quantify social impact investment potential. That’s an exciting
thought. But I suggest it will only be possible once somebody has managed to
remind us to care about our neighbors—and maybe there’s a Nobel Prize waiting for
that person too.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.